HOME JOURNALS CONTACT

Asian Journal of Marketing

Year: 2009 | Volume: 3 | Issue: 2 | Page No.: 52-64
DOI: 10.3923/ajm.2009.52.64
An Empirical Examination of the Reasons Governing Multiple Unit Franchise Adoption in Australia
Scott Weaven

Abstract: This study examines reasons why multiple unit franchising arrangements are adopted from a franchisor perspective. Based on the resource constraints and agency literatures a set of seven hypothesis explaining the choice of multiple unit franchising from a franchisor’s perspective are derived and subjected to empirical assessment. The analysis is carried out using a sample of 114 Australian franchisors. Significant differences between prior explanations of the motivational incentives governing multiple unit adoption and practice within the Australian franchising sector were found. Results indicate that franchisors appear to approach the selection, recruitment and management of multiple unit franchisees in an ad hoc fashion that may have a deleterious effect upon the ongoing management of the franchising relationship. Implications for managerial action and future research direction are discussed.

Fulltext PDF Fulltext HTML

How to cite this article
Scott Weaven , 2009. An Empirical Examination of the Reasons Governing Multiple Unit Franchise Adoption in Australia. Asian Journal of Marketing, 3: 52-64.

Keywords: Multiple unit franchising, resource constraints theory, agency theory and corporatization

INTRODUCTION

Multiple Unit Franchising (MUF) is an organizational arrangement in which franchisees are permitted to own and operate more than one unit within the same franchise system (Grunhagen and Mittelstaedt, 2005). Several negative and positive aspects of multiple unit franchising have been proposed. For example, multiple unit franchising necessitates the employment of unit level managers and resultant adverse selection and moral hazard effects may have a deleterious effect upon operational efficiency (Shane, 1995). However, multiple unit franchising has been described to have positive associations with system growth rates, system-wide adaptation to competition, channel member communication and system uniformity (Dant and Gundlach, 1999; Bradach, 1995; Kaufmann and Dant et al., 1996). This may explain, why over half of all franchise units are owned by multiple unit franchisees in the US (IFA Educational Foundation, 2002), but does not explain why similar rates of acceptance are not observable in Australia (Frazer et al., 2006). Therefore, the conventional wisdom explaining multiple unit adoption may not capture the full range of incentives governing multiple unit adoption in the Australian franchising sector.

This study adopts an agency-theoretic perspective to explain this franchising choice from the franchisor’s perspective. Following a review of the literature, an explicit set of seven hypothesis is presented. The hypotheses are empirically evaluated with survey data collected from a sample of franchisors. This research makes a significant contribution to theory and presents important implications for practice by integrating known concepts with newly identified motivational incentives that drive or inhibit the adoption of this organizational arrangement.

Company Owned Units Versus Franchising Choice
Two important theories have been presented to explain a franchisor’s choice of franchising as a method of expansion rather than growth through company owned units. The first, resource constraints theory, endorses the choice of franchising as a method of extending capital (Combs and Ketchen, 1999; Oxenfeldt and Kelly, 1968-1969), labor (Norton, 1988a, b) managerial (Combs and Castrogiovanni, 1994) and local market knowledge (Minkler, 1990) limitations on future growth. The more accepted theory, agency theory, explains the choice of the franchising form as an effective response to agency and motivational problems associated with geographically dispersed units (Brickley and Dark, 1987). Under this theory franchisors judge franchisees, as residual claimants, to be more highly motivated to follow their decisions and policies than would employee managers (Michael, 1996; Wattel, 1968; McGuire and Matta, 2003). Given that multiple unit franchising arrangements conceptually mirror company-owned operations, most prior research has adopted an agency framework in explaining this organizational arrangement (Garg et al., 2005).

Multiple Unit Franchising Versus Single Unit Choice
The advantages of multiple unit franchising has been assessed in relation to the role of capital acquisition, agency cost minimization and upstream price competition (Kaufmann and Dant, 1996; Kalnins and Lafontaine, 2004). However, past studies may not capture a full range of motivations and some results appear to be inconsistent with what is observed in practice. For example, many larger and older franchisors favor single unit growth strategies (Frazer and Weaven, 2004; Frazer and McCosker, 1999), which contrasts with the findings of research conducted in the United States (Grunhagen and Mittelstaedt, 2005; Garg et al., 2005). Given this disparity, a thorough investigation into the reasons that justify the existence of multiple unit franchising forms from the perspective of the franchisor is warranted. Therefore, this research investigates the research question:

What are the motivational incentives and factors that influence franchisors to adopt MUF in Australia?

Franchise System Maturity
Earlier research suggests that more experienced franchisors apportion less risk to the development of mini-chains within their system than the managers of systems in the early stages of their life-cycle (Kalnins and Lafontaine, 2004; Bradach, 1995). Less experienced franchisors should perceive multiple unit franchisees as entailing greater risk than owner operators as the formation of a relationship with an unreliable party could do more harm to the system than single unit failures (Dant and Nasr, 1998; Kaufmann and Dant, 1998). Although the size of franchisee-owned mini-chains in Australia may negate double marginalization inefficiencies (Lafontainne and Slade, 2001), managers of firms at an early stage of development may be inclined to conclude that the advantages associated with rapid capital access and market penetration, are outweighed by the risk of failure. Therefore, it is predicted that:

H1.1: There is a positive relationship between MUF and franchise system maturity.

Franchise System Corporatization
Given that maturing and therefore increasingly professional systems engage in multiple unit franchising (Robicheaux et al., 1994; Kaufmann and Kim, 1995), it is reasonable to assume that the standardization of functional aspects of the firm’s operation would be both necessary and advantageous to a franchisor adopting this growth strategy (Floyd and Fenwick, 1999). Franchise system corporatization refers to the process of turning a proprietor-led business into one that is governed by a formal management structure, defined by skill sets, job roles and strategic planning (Weaven and Frazer, 2007a). It follows that these organizational characteristics will influence the perceived attractiveness of the franchise system to potential incumbents and govern the strategic management of the firm and the selection, recruitment, training and ongoing support given to chain franchisees (Weaven and Frazer, 2007b). Thus, the above arguments give rise to the following hypothesis:

H1.2: There is a positive relationship between MUF and the degree of franchise system corporatisation.

Plurality of Distribution
Prior research shows that plural distribution (a combination of franchised and company-owned units) is effective in providing additional information to franchisors (Bradach and Eccles, 1989), maintaining control and consistency (Lafontaine, 1992) and ensuring product and service quality (Scott, 1995). Given that multiple unit structures use employee managers within the subsystem mini-chains (Garg et al., 2005), the transference from company to multiple unit ownership should encompass fewer transitional costs. In addition, company-owned units promote the refinement of existing routines and franchisor management practices (Yin and Zajac, 2004; Sorenson and Sorensen, 2001). As multiple unit franchisee operations approximate franchisor operations (Kaufmann and Dant, 1996; Dant and Gundlach, 1999), it may be beneficial for franchisors to maintain company operations to inform mini-chain operations in areas such as spans of control, staff recruitment and performance evaluation processes and operations reporting schemes (Garg et al., 2005). However, there is some evidence that company ownership by Australian-based franchisors is significantly lower than reported overseas (Pricewaterhouse Coopers, 2004; Frazer et al., 2006). Therefore, an examination of the relationship between dual distribution arrangements and multiple unit ownership is warranted:

H1.3: There is a positive relationship between MUF and franchise systems characterized by plural forms of distribution.

Intra-Firm Conflict
Informal provisions within the franchising contract, together with the existence of bargaining, imply that conflict exists in franchising arrangements (Dant and Schul, 1992). As multiple unit franchisees tend to strictly replicate franchisor management guidelines and processes (Kaufmann and Dant, 1996; Bradach, 1995), this informality may be negatively perceived as a weakness in the investment opportunity. In addition, the existence of conflict may indicate a franchisor’s ineffectual management of the franchising relationship (Baucus et al., 1996; Hunt and Nevin, 1974; Lewis and Lambert, 1991). Should franchisors be unable to enlist the cooperation of existing franchisees to operationalize their goals then it would be unlikely that the franchisor would allow them to increase their holdings (and power) within the franchise system.

Furthermore, franchisors that were unsuccessful in realizing small scale economies at the unit level would be less willing to subjugate administrative power to new multiple unit franchisees, unless they could confidently predict the future success of these franchisees. As the existence of conflict may be indicative of poor selection and recruitment processes (Jambulingam and Nevin, 1999), it would be reasonable to conjecture that these processes would be ineffective in choosing suitable multiple unit candidates. Thus, it is hypothesized that:

H1.4: There is a negative relationship between MUF and the level of conflict within the franchise system.

Geographic Dispersion of Units
From an agency perspective, one would assume that even if a multiple unit franchisee’s goals were perfectly aligned with that of the franchisor, at some level of organizational complexity (Hall, 1977), monitoring information would become inaccurate (Brickley and Dark, 1987). Therefore, a franchisor would most likely favor sales of contiguous units to a multiple unit franchisee. This action would promote monitoring economies within the chain organization by reducing the geographical dispersion of franchisee units. Although, empirical research in the United States supports this contention (Kalnins and Lafontaine, 2004), some franchisors in Australia appear reluctant to sell units in close proximity (especially within urban localities) due to quality benefits associated with intra-system competition issues (Bolton, 2002). This has some support in the organizational governance literature examining the relationship between service quality and intra-system competition in asymmetrical exchange relationships (Sorenson and Sorensen, 2001), but to date has not yet been examined in the Australian context. In an attempt to clarify this apparent contradiction in franchising theory and practice it is hypothesized that:

H1.5: There is a positive relationship between MUF and the availability of geographically contiguous franchisee units.

Reward Strategy
It is possible that multiple unit arrangements enable franchisors to exert motivational control over sequential franchisees wishing to expand. This may give them leverage in control of quality deviations that could result in performance decay and concept deterioration (Bercovitz, 2004; Kaufmann, 1990; Kaufmann and Kim, 1995). Bercovitz (2004) suggested that multiple unit franchising strategies are effective in reducing opportunistic franchisee behaviours by raising ex-post rent expectations within self-enforcing franchising contracts (Williamson, 1985). However, Australian franchise systems do not favor sequential modes of expansion due to issues surrounding managerial and administrative capability and experience (Weaven and Frazer, 2007a). However, it appears plausible that the lure of multiple unit ownership would be beneficial in manipulating franchisee commitment to the system resulting in the minimization of shirking and free-riding behaviours. Thus, it is hypothesized that:

H1.6: There is a positive relationship between MUF and system reward strategies.

Franchise System Growth
The chief advantage associated with multiple unit expansion is its association with accelerated system growth, increases in profitability and long term survival (Bradach, 1995; Kaufmann and Kim, 1995; Kaufmann and Dant, 1996). However, the literature on multiple unit franchising and system growth is sometimes unclear. For example, research by Kaufmann and Dant (1996) suggested that multiple unit franchising arrangements do not handle agency related expenses (such as adverse selection and moral hazard) as well as single unit expansionary strategies. In contrast, recent research by Garg et al. (2005) suggested that relative growth advantages exist for multiple unit franchising over single forms of franchise governance in terms of generating closer incentives alignment between agent and principal. However, most prior research has tended to examine multiple unit growth strategies through the assessment of a single derivation of master franchising (that is, area development agreements) (Kaufmann and Dant, 1996) which is only receiving limited acceptance in the Australian market. Thus, previous analyses overseas may not fully accord with the reasons governing growth strategies and methods in the Australian franchising sector. Thus, it is hypothesized that:

H1.7: There is a positive relationship between MUF and firm growth.

MATERIALS AND METHODS

The Franchise Council of Australia (FCA) granted permission to include questions within the Franchising Australia survey in 2004 (administered in April/May 2004 by Griffith University), which is a biennial survey conducted throughout all states and territories of Australia. The resultant data were analyzed to test a set of hypothesis of franchisor motivations to adopt multiple unit franchising arrangements. Inferential statistical tests were used to test the hypothesized relationships. From 540 questionnaires, 114 useable responses were received giving a response rate of 21%, which is similar to those obtained in earlier surveys (for example, Frazer and McCosker, 1999).

Operationalization of VariablesMultiple Unit Versus Single Unit Grouping and Franchisee Density
Two dependent variables were developed to reflect the choice of multiple unit systems versus single unit systems. A simple dichotomous variable was used which simply measured whether a system contained no multiple units (hereinafter termed the single unit group), or contained any number of multiple units (hereinafter termed the multiple unit group). Just under a third of the sample (35 systems) did not allow multiple unit franchising.

A second dependent measure was also developed for those systems which contained multiple units-The Franchisee Density Index. This provided an index of the degree to which multiple unit franchising had been adopted within systems containing multiple units. The Franchisee Density Index was calculated as the ratio of the number of franchisees within the system divided by the number of franchise units within the system. Sixty five systems within the sample had one or more multiple units. For the multiple unit group, the index ranged in value from 0.10 to 0.99 (Mean = 0.78, SD = 0.23). Both skew and kurtosis were found to significantly deviate from normality. Procedures described by Tabachnick and Fidell (2001) were followed. The variable was first reverse scored and then a square-root transformation applied. Skew was still significant so a log transformation was applied. Following this transformation the value for both skew (-0.16, p>0.01) and kurtosis (-0.42, p>0.01) were found to not significantly deviate from normality. The variable was then again reverse scored to maintain the rank order of the original untransformed variable.

Franchisor Experience
This variable was operationalized as the number of years the franchisor had been franchising. The tests of normality on the group data showed no significant deviation from normality.

Degree of Corporatisation
Respondents were asked to indicate if they had a company board of at least five members, had two or more appointed board members who were external to the firm, had a marketing department, or had at least one franchise on the board. A composite variable was produced as the sum of responses across these four dichotomous variables with a possible range in values from 0 to 4.

Plurality of Distribution
This variable was operationalized as a dichotomous variable by grouping systems as those that either did or did not contain company owned units.

Intra-Firm Conflict
This was a dichotomous variable indicating whether or not the franchisors were in conflict with any franchise in the system.

Geographical Dispersion of Units
Units were coded on an ordinal scale: 0 = Neighboring suburbs, 1 = same city and 2 = not same city.

Reward Strategy
Dichotomous variable indicating whether or not the franchisors viewed rewards as important.

System Growth
This index was calculated by taking the difference in the number of franchise units in the system between the survey year and the value for two years earlier divided by the base level of the survey year. Due to significant levels of both skew and kurtosis, the variable was reverse scored, the log taken and the variable reverse scored again (Tabachnick and Fidell, 2001). This produced a transformed variable with acceptable levels of skew (skew = -0.676, p>0.01) but which still exhibited a significant departure from normality with respect to kurtosis (kurtosis = 7.29, p<0.01).

RESULTS

Descriptive Statistics
Slightly more than half of the respondents (57%) reported that they encouraged suitable franchisees to own multiple units within their system and 41 (36%) reported that they granted area development rights to franchisees. Nearly one third of the franchisor respondents (32%) reported that their franchisees had between one and three years’ franchising experience before they were granted additional units within the franchise system. Overall, more than half of the franchisors (52%) felt that multiple unit franchisees required the same level of support as single unit franchisees.

Inferential Statistics
The results of the inferential tests of hypotheses are provided in Table 1. For each hypothesis inferential tests were performed in two ways. First, comparisons were made of single unit systems versus systems that contained multiple unit franchisees. These comparisons allowed tests of whether the hypothesized independent variables had any influence on the choice by franchisors to allow multiple unit franchising within their system. Second, for the systems containing multiple unit franchisees, the relationship between Franchisee Density Index scores could be made with other variables. These comparisons allowed tests to evaluate whether the hypothesized independent variables had any influence on the extent to which multiple unit franchising was adopted once the decision had been made by the franchisor to allow multiple unit franchising within their system.


Table 1: Results of Inferrential Tests of Hypotheses a

aTwo comparisons are made for each hypothesis using one of two independent variables. (a) The dependent variable is a dichotomous variable which groups franchisors as either single unit indicating there to be no multiple units in their system, or as multiple unit, (b) The dependent variable is metric, the Franchise Density Index (FDI) and is calculated for franchisors in the multiple unit group only, bDifferent results are shown in the pattern of results as each variable utilized different measurement scales (as specified in the materials and method section). N/A: Not applicable

The specific inferential test used to test each hypothesis varied as a function of the scale of measurement of the two variables in a specific analysis. When both variables were non-metric, a contingency table (Chi-square) analysis was conducted. When one variable was metric and the other non-metric, an Analysis of Variance (ANOVA) was conducted. When both variables were metric a Pearson product-moment correlation was conducted. The results of these analyses are provided in Table 1.

Organizations within which multiple unit franchising was occurring had been operating as franchisors for a significantly longer period (Mean = 11.13 years) than had organizations where only single unit franchising was reported (Mean = 6.35 years), F (1,96) = 13.53, p<0.0005. This result supports hypothesis H1.1. Partial support was also found for this hypothesis within the multiple unit group with a correlation between years of franchising and the franchise density index approaching significance (r = 0.243, p = 0.05).

Significant relationships were also found between franchising and intra-firm conflict as predicted by hypothesis H1.4. The effects, however, were in the reverse direction to that hypothesized. A contingency table analysis found there to be a significant relationship between intra-firm conflict (in dispute/not in dispute) and system grouping (single/multiple), χ2 (1, n = 100) = 5.51, p>0.05. Only 6% of franchisors from single-unit systems reported there to be conflict between the franchisor and one or more of the franchisees, whereas for multi-unit systems, 25% of franchisors reported the existence of conflict. This pattern was also found with respect to variation in the Franchise Density Index across m ultiple unit systems. A significant effect was found for intra-firm conflict, F(1,63) = 7.70, p<0.01, with higher mean density scores being displayed for systems which are in conflict (Mean = 2.71) compared with systems which were not in conflict (Mean = 1.87). No other significant relationships were found.

DISCUSSION

This study explored franchisor incentives for multiple unit franchising and the implications arising from the study are discussed below. The results from the quantitative analysis found support for the proposed link between franchise system maturity and multiple unit franchising (H1.1) and is consistent with previous research (Robicheaux et al., 1994; Kaufmann and Dant, 1996; Wadsworth, 2002). Unlike systems in the early stages of their life-cycle, more experienced franchisors are likely to appeal to new franchisees as they have an established reputation and brand, proven concept and track record of performance and managerial acumen. In addition, multiple unit franchising may be more popular in older franchise systems due to the needs of incumbent franchisees. In practice, franchisors may attempt to promote franchisee satisfaction and maximize unit level performance through allowing multiple unit ownership.

The proposed relationship between the degree of franchise system corporatisation and multiple unit franchising was not supported (H1.2). This lack of support may indicate that franchisors that encourage multiple unit ownership do not necessarily perceive managerial and functional structural differentiation as important in attracting investment from prospective and existing franchisees. Most franchisors continue to favor sequential modes of multiple unit expansion (Frazer and Weaven, 2002; Frazer et al., 2006) which contrasts markedly with United States franchisors (Kaufmann and Dant, 1996). The founders of many franchise systems may be reluctant to encourage a process of corporatisation as it may reduce their power and levels of personal control within the system and may believe that an autocratic management style is necessary to maintain decision-making flexibility, especially in an environment characterized by high demand uncertainty.

There was a similar lack of support for the agency costs argument (H1.3). One possible explanation for this lack of support would be that franchisors are unaware of the complementary benefits of higher innovation and coordination gains associated with dual-distribution networks (Michael, 1996; Bradach, 1998; Cliquet, 2001; Lafontaine and Shaw, 2001). However, franchisors that encourage multiple unit ownership may feel that the maintenance of system-wide standards are less important in companies with multiple unit ownership as franchisees are less likely to free-ride off other units within their own subsystems (Gal-Or, 1995; Dant and Gundlach, 1999).

Although, a negative association between intra-firm conflict and multiple unit franchising was proposed (H1.4), a significant positive relationship was found. Franchisors find it difficult to attract suitable franchisee candidates (Frazer et al., 2006) and may find it easier to encourage existing single unit franchisees to become multiple unit holders, even though these franchisees may not have the managerial skills, knowledge or financial resources to commit to additional units. This may minimize ex-ante costs associated with the recruitment and selection of candidates, but may have a deleterious impact upon the future operational efficiency of franchisee-owned subsystems.

The positive relationship between the geographic proximity of franchised units and the use of multiple unit franchising strategies was not supported (H1.5). This finding is inconsistent with prior research conducted overseas (Kalnins and Lafontaine, 2004) suggested that Australian franchisors’ operational strategies are unique. Franchisors appear to actively discourage ownership of geographically close units, perhaps as it negates the benefits associated with the maintenance of beneficial levels of benchmarking (Sorenson and Sorensen, 2001) and competition between incumbent franchisees (Brown, 1998; Bolton, 2002).

Similarly, the proposed relationship between system reward strategies and multiple unit franchising (H1.6) was not significant which is in contrast to previous research reported overseas (Bercovitz, 2004). Franchisors may be reactive rather than proactive in allowing successful franchisees to increase their unit holdings in the system. Although, the granting of additional units may be viewed by franchisees as rewards for good performance, franchisors may not explicitly offer them as rewards.

Whereas earlier research has confirmed the relationship between multiple unit franchising and system growth (Kaufmann and Kim, 1995; Kaufmann and Dant, 1996), hypothesis H1.7 was unsupported in this research. Whilst some multiple unit arrangements in the United States encompass many hundreds of outlets (Grunhagen and Mittelstaedt, 2002), Australian systems are typically smaller (typically 1-2 units, Frazer and Weaven, 2004) and may be unable to satisfy size requirements in attaining operational efficiencies. Earlier research suggests that franchisee-owned mini-chains incorporating only two or three outlets may suffer from performance decay as the potential for operational synergies (in purchasing, management and administrative costs) are not realizable in the short term (Kaufmann, 1992). Future research should examine optimum unit allocation strategies within multiple unit franchising arrangements (and within the context of different strategic priorities (Garg et al., 2005; Bradach, 1995) so, as to identify methods of maximizing mini-chain efficiency.

One limitation of this study arises as a consequence of bias resulting from self-complete surveys. In particular, measurement error may result from inaccuracies in a respondent’s reporting of data. In addition as data were collected from Australia, the generalizability of results may not extend beyond this region. Replication in other global settings is recommended to resolve this limitation. Furthermore, non-response bias could not be tested due to the anonymous nature of the survey.

This study has important implications for practitioners. The results suggest that Australian franchisors have unique motivations for encouraging franchisee subsystem development. Australian franchisors appear to utilize ad hoc methods of expansion n an attempt to grow system units as their compensation is directly linked to growth in sales. More mature systems appear to encourage multiple unit ownership, although, the results suggest that this may not be due to their ability to offer structural arrangements conducive to attracting external investment, but may be due to a willingness to apportion less risk to this form of expansion. While, this research hypothesized strategic motives for this endeavor, the real reasons why multiple unit arrangements exist and continue to grow, may be due to a franchisor’s desire to grow the size of their system, or more realistically, just survive. However, this may prove to be a non-sustaining strategy due to the increasing level of substantial disputation in systems characterized by multiple unit ownership.

Although, there was minimal support for the hypothesized relationships, this research may be useful in providing some preliminary answers as to when to engage in multiple unit franchising, who should engage in multiple unit franchising and why franchisors should encourage the growth of franchisee-owned subsystems. This should help minimize franchisee and franchisor dissatisfaction associated with the adoption of hybridized franchising forms based upon operational and structural incompatibility and competing expectations. This, in turn, should minimize failure and result in the growth of workable and efficient franchise systems. In addition, the results could be used to inform managers of the expansionary outcomes associated with a given proportion of multiple unit franchising within the context of factors moderating acceptance. Managers can use this information to determine how compatible these determinants are within the context of firm-level strategic priorities.

CONCLUSION

The research findings infer that the conventional wisdom explaining multiple unit franchising may not adequately explain the reasons influencing the growth of franchisee-owned mini-chains Australian franchising systems. In particular, the inconsistency in the results of this research and other studies suggests that sectoral and firm-level differences between countries may impact upon the popularity and successful management of different types of franchisee-owned mini-chains. Although, prior research posits positive agency and growth - related outcomes with multiple unit adoption, Australian franchisors’ growing endorsement of this strategy may reflect current economic conditions characterized by difficulties in attracting suitable franchisee candidates and realizing minimum efficient scales of operation.

ACKNOWLEDGMENT

The author would like to thank Griffith University and the Franchise Council of Australia for their assistance in this research project.

REFERENCES

  • Robicheaux, R.A., R. Dant and P. Kaufmann, 1994. Multiple unit franchising in the fast food industry in the united states: Incidence and operating characteristics. Paper Read at 8th Conference of the Society of Franchising, February, at Las Vegas, USA.


  • Baucus, D.A., M.S. Baucus and S.E. Human, 1996. Consensus in franchise organisations: A cooperative arrangement among entrepreneurs. J. Bus. Venturing, 11: 359-378.


  • Scott, Jr. F.A., 1995. Franchising vs. company ownership as a decision variable of the firm. Rev. Ind. Organ., 10: 69-81.
    CrossRef    


  • Bercovitz, J.E.L., 2004. The Organisational Choice Decision in Business Format Franchising: An Empirical Test. In: Economics and Management of Franchising Networks, Windsperger, J., G.G. Cliquet Hendrikse and M. Tuunanen (Eds.). Strategy and Governance of Newtworks, New York, Springer-Verlag, pp: 38-68


  • Wattel, H., 1968. Are franchisors realistic and successful in their selection of franchisees? J. Retail., 44: 54-68.


  • Bradach, J.L., 1995. Chains Within Chains: The Role of Multi-Unit Franchisees. In: Franchising: Contemporary Issues and Research, Kaufmann, P. and R. Dant (Eds.). Haworth Press, New York


  • Bradach, J.L., 1998. Franchise Organizations. 1st Edn., Harvard Business School Press, Boston, ISBN-13: 9780875848327


  • Bradach, J.L. and R.G. Eccles, 1989. Price, authority and trust: From ideal types to plural forms. Ann. Rev. Sociol., 15: 97-118.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Brickley, J.A. and F.H. Dark, 1987. The choice of organizational form the case of franchising. J. Financ. Econ., 18: 401-420.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Brown, Jr. W.O., 1998. Transaction costs, corporate hierarchies and the theory of franchising. J. Econ. Behav. Organ., 36: 317-327.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Cliquet, G., 2001. Plural forms in store networks: A model for store network evolution. Int. Rev. Retail Distribut. Consumer Res., 10: 369-387.
    CrossRef    


  • Combs, J.G. and G.J. Castrogiovanni, 1994. Franchising strategy: A proposed model and empirical test of franchise versus company ownership. J. Small Bus. Manage., 32: 37-48.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Combs, J.G. and D.J. Ketchen, 1999. Explaining interfirm cooperation and performance: Toward a reconciliation of predictions from the resource-based view and organizational economics. Strategic Manage. J., 20: 867-888.
    CrossRef    


  • Dant, R.P. and G.T. Gundlach, 1999. The challenge of autonomy and dependence in franchised channels of distribution. J. Bus. Venturing, 14: 35-68.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Dant, R.P. and N.I. Nasr, 1998. Control techniques and upward flow of information in franchising in distant markets: Conceptualization and preliminary evidence. J. Bus. Venturing, 13: 3-28.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Dant, R.P., A.K. Paswan and P.J. Kaufman, 1996. What we know about ownership redirection in franchising: A meta-analysis. J. Retailing, 72: 429-444.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Dant, R.P. and P.L. Schul, 1992. Conflict resolution processes in contractual channels of distribution. J. Market., 56: 38-54.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Floyd, C. and G. Fenwick, 1999. Towards a model of franchise system development. Int. Small Bus. J., 17: 32-48.
    Direct Link    


  • Frazer, L. and S. Weaven, 2004. Franchising Australia 2004 Survey. Griffith University, Brisbane


  • Frazer, L., S. Weaven and O. Wright, 2006. Franchising Australia 2006. Franchise Council of Australia/Griffith University, Brisbane


  • Gal-Or, E., 1995. Maintaining quality standards in franchise chains. Manage. Sci., 41: 1774-1792.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Garg, V.K., A.A. Rasheed and R.L. Priem, 2005. Explaining franchisors' choices of organizational forms within franchise systems. Strategic. Organ., 3: 185-217.
    CrossRef    


  • Grunhagen, M. and R. Millelstaedt, 2002. Is bigger better: The anticipation of scale efficiencies and decision participation as motivations for aspiring multiple unit franchisees. Int. J. Entrepreneurial Behav. Res., 8: 188-200.
    CrossRef    


  • Grunhagen, M. and R.A. Mittelstaedt, 2005. Entrepreneurs or investors: Do multi-unit franchisees have different philosophical orientations. J. Small Bus. Manage., 43: 207-225.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Hall, R., 1977. Organizations: Structure and Process. 3rd Edn., Prentice Hall, Englewood Cliffs


  • Hunt, S.D. and J.R. Nevin, 1974. Power in a channel of distribution: Sources and consequences. J. Market. Res., 1: 186-193.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • IFA Educational Foundation, 2002. Multi-Unit Owners Study. International Franchise Association Educational Foundation, Washington DC


  • Jambulingam, T. and J.R. Nevin, 1999. Influence of franchisee selection criteria on outcomes desired by the franchisor. J. Bus. Venturing, 14: 363-395.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Kalnins, A. and F. Lafontaine, 2004. Multi-unit ownership in franchising: Evidence from the fast-food industry in texas. RAND J. Econ., 35: 747-761.
    CrossRef    


  • Kaufmann, P., 1992. The impact of managerial performance decay on franchisors' store allocation strategies. J. Market. Channels, 1: 51-79.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Kaufmann, P.J. and R.P. Dant, 1996. Multi-unit franchising: Growth and management issues. J. Bus. Venturing, 11: 343-358.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Kaufmann, P.J. and R.P. Dant, 1999. Franchising and the domain of entrepreneurship research. J. Bus. Venturing, 14: 5-16.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Kaufmann, P.J. and S.H. Kim, 1995. Master Franchising and System Growth Rates. In: Franchising: Contemporary Issues and Research, Kaufmann, P.J. and R.P. Dant (Eds.). Harwood Press, New York, pp: 49-64


  • Lafontaine, F. and K.L. Shaw, 2001. Targeting Managerial Control: Evidence from Franchising. National Bureau of Economic Reseach Inc., NBER


  • Lafontainne, F. and M.E. Slade, 2001. Incentive Contracting and the Franchise Decision. In: Game Theory and Business Applications, Chatterjee, K. and W. Samuelson (Eds.). Kluwer Academic Press, Boston, ISBN: 978-0-7923-7332-2


  • McGuire, J. and E. Matta, 2003. Ceo stock options: The silent dimension of ownership. Acad. Manage. J., 46: 255-265.
    Direct Link    


  • Michael, S.C., 1996. To franchise or not to franchise: An analysis of decision rights and organizational form shares. J. Bus. Venturing, 11: 57-71.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Minkler, A.P., 1990. An empirical analysis of a firm's decision to franchise. Econ. Lett., 34: 77-82.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Norton, S., 1988. An empirical look at franchising as an organisational form. J. Bus., 61: 197-218.
    Direct Link    


  • Norton, S., 1988. Franchising, brand name capital and the entrepreneurial capacity problem. Strategic Manage. J., 9: 105-114.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Sorenson, O. and J.B. Sorensen, 2001. Finding the right mix: Organisational learning, plural forms and franchise performance. Strategic Manage. J., 22: 713-724.
    Direct Link    


  • Tabachnick, B.G. and L.S. Fidell, 2001. Using Multivariate Statistics. 4th Edn., Allyn and Bacon, Boston, MA., USA


  • Wadsworth, F., 2002. Multi-Unit Owners Study. IFA Educational Foundation, Washington DC, USA


  • Weaven, S. and L. Frazer, 2007. Expansion through multiple unit franchising: Australian franchisors reveal their motivations. Int. Small Bus. J., 25: 173-205.
    CrossRef    


  • Weaven, S. and L. Frazer, 2007. Mature franchise systems use multiple unit franchising to leverage learning economies and sustain systemwide growth. Asia Pacific J. Market. Logist., 19: 107-126.
    CrossRef    


  • Williamson, O.E., 1985. The Economic Institutions of Capitalism. 1st Edn., Free Press, New York, USA., ISBN: 978-0684863740, Pages: 468


  • Yin, X. and E. Zajac, 2004. The strategy/governance structure fit relationship: Theory and evidence in franchising arrangements. Strategic Manage. J., 25: 365-383.
    Direct Link    


  • Bolton, M., 2002. Effective local store marketing. Paper Read at Queensland Franchise Forum, March, at Brisbane, Australia.


  • Frazer, L. and C. McCosker, 1999. Franchising Australia 1999: A survey of franchising practices and performance. University of Southern Queensland/Franchise Council of Australia, Toowoomba, pp: 44.


  • Kaufmann, P.J., 1990. A comparison of various methods of franchise expansion. Paper Read at 4th Annual Conference of the Society of Franchising, at Scottsdale, Arizona.


  • Lafontaine, F., 1992. How and why do franchisors do what they do? Paper Read at 6th Annual Society of Franchising Conference, Franchising: Passport for Growth, at Lincoln, New England.


  • Lewis, M.C. and D.M. Lambert, 1991. A model of channel member performance, dependence and satisfaction. J. Retail., 67: 205-225.
    Direct Link    


  • Oxenfeldt, A.R. and A.O. Kelly, 1968. Will successful franchise systems ultimately become wholly-owned chains? J. Retail., 44: 69-83.


  • Pricewaterhouse Coopers, 2004. Economic Impact of Franchised Businesses. Vol. 2. IFA Educational Foundation, Washington, DC
    Direct Link    


  • Frazer, L. and S. Weaven, 2002. Franchising Australia 2002 survey. Griffith University/Franchise Council of Australia Ltd. http://images.thewebconsole.com/S3WEB687/files/4c3265f066447.pdf.

  • © Science Alert. All Rights Reserved