HOME JOURNALS CONTACT

Information Technology Journal

Year: 2017 | Volume: 16 | Issue: 1 | Page No.: 17-26
DOI: 10.3923/itj.2017.17.26
Models of Dualistic Complementary Knowledge Transfer in Big-data Environments
Chuanrong Wu

Abstract: Background: With the advent of the big-data era, it is widely accepted that enterprises need to transfer private knowledge and big-data knowledge at the same time. These two types of knowledge are usually complementary and it is necessary to consider their mutual influence on the efficiency of knowledge transfer. Materials and Methods: Based on studies of independent knowledge transfer, models of dualistic complementary knowledge-transfer are presented to determine the maximum profits of knowledge transfer. Results: The results were the same as those of previous studies in which the mutual influence of private and big-data knowledge was not considered and the model used in the present study is found to be valid. Forecasts were developed for different influence coefficients and dualistic complementary knowledge weights. Profits and transfer costs increased with the influence coefficient of dualistic complementary knowledge. When the weight of big-data knowledge was enhanced, profits increased but transfer costs declined. The results of the simulation experiment used in the present study are consistent with an actual economic situation. Conclusion: It is suggested that enterprises should take into consideration the mutual influence of dualistic complementary knowledge and determine the appropriate proportion of dualistic complementary knowledge according to the degree of mutual influence and discounted profits when transferring knowledge in a big-data environment.

Fulltext PDF Fulltext HTML

How to cite this article
Chuanrong Wu , 2017. Models of Dualistic Complementary Knowledge Transfer in Big-data Environments. Information Technology Journal, 16: 17-26.

Keywords: efficiency, Big data, knowledge transfer, complementary knowledge and optimization model

INTRODUCTION

Knowledge is one of the most important elements of core competence in today’s economy and firms try to transfer and absorb it in each interaction within their environments1,2. The process of enterprises absorbing, applying and creating knowledge through various channels is called knowledge transfer3. Scholars have conducted numerous studies on knowledge transfer from different perspectives. Research has shown that inter-firm cooperative agreements provide opportunities for knowledge transfer and firm’s partners in their cooperative actions are primary environmental or external sources of knowledge4-6. Previous studies have focused on such external environment characteristics of knowledge transfer as knowledge transfer in strategic alliances, industrial clusters and innovation networks7-19.

With the rapid development of the internet, networking, social networks and cloud computing, the era of the big data has begun. The use of big-data has become the basis of competition and growth for individual enterprises. It can enhance productivity and create significant value for enterprises by guiding decision-making, trimming costs and increasing the quality of products and services20,21. Useful knowledge mined by agencies and personnel specializing in big-data is an important part of the knowledge that enterprises need for innovation22-26 and this type of knowledge can be called big-data knowledge.

In a big-data environment, enterprises need to transfer private knowledge from other organizations and to transfer big-data knowledge27. Private knowledge and big-data knowledge are the dominant types of knowledge that enterprises need for innovation in big-data environments. However, because big-data knowledge is characterized as open-source, dynamic and massive and because it has multisource heterogeneity28, the process of big-data knowledge transfer is different from that of private knowledge transfer.

The most common type of private knowledge is core patent knowledge and the most common type of big-data knowledge is non-core patent knowledge. These two types of knowledge are usually not independent. If the relationship between private knowledge and big-data knowledge is competitive, an enterprise will usually choose to transfer the big-data knowledge because it is cheaper and easier to acquire. Only when big-data knowledge cannot be obtained or involves violations of intellectual property rights will an enterprise transfer private knowledge from another organization29. Therefore, when the two types of knowledge are complementary, the enterprise will transfer the private knowledge and the big-data knowledge at the same time in a big-data environment. It is necessary to consider the mutual influence of these two types of complementary knowledge on the efficiency of knowledge transfer. However, at the moment, there are few studies on complementary knowledge transfer in big-data environments.

This study tries to identify the influence of these two types of complementary knowledge on knowledge-transfer efficiency.

MATERIALS AND METHODS

When an enterprise only needs to transfer two types of knowledge in a big-data environment and one type of knowledge is private knowledge from another enterprise while the other type is big-data knowledge from a big-data knowledge provider, the relationship between the two types of knowledge is complementary.

Model hypotheses: The model used in the present study is compared with models developed in previous study. Assumptions and variables remain unchanged. The expression of the dynamic knowledge network is G = (V, E, BD), Vi and Vj represent the two enterprises in G = (V, E, BD). The Vi produces only one product and transfers one type of private knowledge from Vj and one type of big-data knowledge from BD; ω1, ω2 (0<ω1, ω2<1, ω12 = 1) is the weight of private knowledge and big-data knowledge. The update rate of private knowledge is β1, the update rate of the big-data knowledge is β2 and the total update rate of external knowledge is β. The total market volume of the product is Q, the price of the product is p, the discount rate is r and the marginal cost in the starting period is MC. The absorption capacity is α(0<α<1) and the market share of each enterprise in the starting period is N. The total market volume increases at a rate of θ1(0<θ1<1) in the first L1 periods and decreases at a rate of θ(0<θ<1) in other periods. The growth rate of the market share of Vi is ρ1(0<θ11<1) in the first L periods when Vi only transfers private knowledge. The ρ2(0<θ12<1) is the growth rate of the market share of Vi in the first L periods when Vi only transfers big-data knowledge. The ρ(0<θ1<ρ<1) is the growth rate of the market share of Vi in the first L1 periods immediately after knowledge transfer. The lifecycle of the product is N; the detailed assumptions refer to Wu et al.27 and Wu and Zeng30. Additionally, two new hypotheses are proposed:

Hypothesis 1: The Vi will transfer private knowledge and big-data knowledge at the same time in time period T and private knowledge and big-data knowledge are complementary
Hypothesis 2: The influence coefficient of two types of knowledge is σ(σ>0)

Quantitative expression of mutual influence between dualistic complementary types of knowledge: Following the previous hypotheses, when an enterprise produces a product using prior knowledge, its marginal cost in the starting period will be MC. The enterprise will accumulate knowledge stock according to the knowledge absorption capacity α(0<α<1). The marginal cost will decline at a rate of (1-α) and the marginal cost in time period n will reduce to MCαn (n<T). When the enterprise adopts new knowledge in time period T, the marginal cost changes from MCαT to MCβT. Then, as the enterprise continues to accumulate production experience based on this marginal cost, the marginal cost in period n will reduce to MCβTαn (n>T).

If two types of knowledge are independent, there is no need to consider the mutual influence of these two types of knowledge accumulating with time. According to the contribution of these two types of knowledge for the enterprise’s innovation, the total update rate of the external knowledge can be determined27 as β = ω1β12β2. Then, the enterprise will continue to accumulate production experience based on this efficiency. When the enterprise adopts new knowledge in time period T, the marginal cost will change from MCαT to MC(ω1β12β2)T and the marginal cost in time period n will reduce to MC(ω1β12β2)Tαn (n>T).

When two types of knowledge are complementary, the enterprise must consider the interaction between the two types of knowledge as it accumulates with time. Knowledge transfer is the process of transferring knowledge from an organization with high knowledge potential energy to an organization with low knowledge potential energy31. Then, mutual influence will relate to the knowledge distance between the two types of complementary knowledge.

The update rate of private knowledge is β1 and the update rate of big-data knowledge is β2. When an enterprise adopts new knowledge in time period T, the update rate of external private knowledge evolves to and the update rate of the external big-data knowledge evolves to in time period T. When the mutual influence of the two types of complementary knowledge is linear and within a certain potential threshold value, following hypothesis 2, the influence coefficient will be σ(σ>0) and the mutual influence can be expressed as . Because the influence of the complementary knowledge is positive, it can be assumed that the enterprise will accumulate production experience with the new efficiency after knowledge transfer; therefore, the update rate of the enterprise in period T can be expressed as:

(1)

Optimization model: Following hypothesis 1, Vi will prefer transferring one type of private knowledge and one type of big-data knowledge at the same time in time period T. ζ(T) is the discount expectation of profits (DEP) of Vi before knowledge transfer, ξ(T) is the DEP of Vi after knowledge transfer and K(T) is the knowledge-transfer cost. The total DEP of Vi can be denoted as ψ(T), such that ψ(T) = ζ(T)+ξ(T)-K(T).

Expected profit before knowledge transfer: Because there is no new knowledge transfer during this period, the method of calculating the DEP before knowledge transfer is the same as given by Wu et al.27, according to which the DEP before knowledge transfer is:

(2)

Transfer cost of dualistic complementary knowledge: Enterprises must pay a certain amount of knowledge-transfer cost when absorbing private knowledge. Similarly, in a big-data environment, enterprises must pay a knowledge-transfer cost when transferring big-data knowledge from big data knowledge providers. In a big-data environment, the knowledge-transfer cost K can be divided into the fixed cost and the variable cost. When an enterprise Vi transfers two types of complementary knowledge at the same time, the fixed transfer cost k should be composed of two parts: The fixed transfer cost of the private knowledge k1 and the fixed transfer cost of the big-data knowledge k2. The ω1, ω2 (0<ω1, ω2<1; ω12 = 1) is the weight of the private knowledge and the big-data knowledge so k = ω1k12k2, where, k1 and k2 are constants.

Variable cost is related to the potential difference between external knowledge and internal knowledge. The potential energy of external knowledge is determined by the interaction of private knowledge and big-data knowledge. The update rate of external knowledge in time period T is shown in Eq. 1, such that the knowledge potential difference can be expressed as Eq. 3:

(3)

The variable cost can be computed by where, F is a constant. By discounting the transfer cost to the beginning after adding the fixed and variable costs, the present value of the knowledge-transfer cost in a big-data environment can be expressed as Eq. 4:

(4)

Expected profits after transferring dualistic complementary knowledge: When the growth rate of market share is not influenced, ω1, ω2 are also the weights of the dualistic complementary knowledge for the growth rate of market share; the growth rate of total market share ρ can be calculated by Eq. 5:

(5)

Following previous hypotheses, the market share of Vi will increase at a rate of ρ in the first L periods immediately after the time period T and then it will decay at a rate of θ. Hence, the market share of Vi in period n is denoted in Eq. 6:

(6)

The knowledge adopted by Vi in time period T is updated by βT, which reduces the marginal cost in time period T to MCβT. From Eq. 1, MCβT can be expressed as By renumbering the periods after knowledge transfer as n starting from 1 to N, the marginal cost in period n becomes . Hence, the total production cost in period n after knowledge transfer is . By subtracting the total production cost from the sales revenue pQλ(n,T), the profit in time period n after knowledge transfer is calculated in Eq. 7:

(7)

Discounting the profits in time period n to the starting point by multiplying Eq. 7 by rT rn and including all the discount profits in period N, the DEP after knowledge transfer is:

(8)

Using Eq. 6 and 8, the expected profits after knowledge transfer can be expressed as Eq. 9:

(9)

Total DEP model: The optimization problem of dualistic complementary knowledge transfer is to find the maximum of ζ(T)+ξ(T)-K(T) within the given parameters. Therefore, the optimization model of knowledge transfer can be expressed as Eq. 10:

(10)

RESULTS

Model solution: Equation 10 shows that ψ(T) is a piecewise continuous differential function of T. Therefore, ψ(T) can reach its maximum in a closed interval 1<T<N and the maximum profit in the lifecycle of the product can be found. Considering the power of the numerical calculation and simulation functions, MATLAB should be used to compile a program. Numerous experiments could be conducted by adjusting the model’s parameters.

Parameter-setting: To simulate an actual situation of knowledge transfer in a big-data environment, certain parameters were chosen for testing. To compare with Wu et al.27 the values of the same parameters are the same as in Wu et al.27 and the new parameters set the new values. These parameters are set as follows: The total product sales is Q = 1000; the relative value of price per unit product is p = 60; the market share of Vi in the starting period is φ = 8%; the growth rate of total market volume in the first L1(L1 = 3) periods is θ1 = 3%; the natural attenuation rate of market volume in the other periods is θ = 3%; the growth rate of the two types of knowledge on market sharein the first L = 5 periods immediately after knowledge transfer is ρ1 = 6%, ρ2 = 8%; the marginal cost in the starting period is MC = 40; the fixed transfer cost is k1 = 300; the fixed transfer cost is k2 = 80; the coefficient of the variable cost is F = 1000; knowledge absorption capacity is α = 95%; the update rate of private knowledge is β1 = 88%; the update rate of big-data knowledge is β2 = 84%; the influence coefficient of dualistic complementary knowledge is σ = 0.5 and the lifecycle of the product is N = 10. Assuming the market risk is neutral, the discount rate is 10% and r = 1/(1+10%)≈0.9.

Validation of the model:

When σ = 0, the influence coefficient between the two types of complementary knowledge is zero, which means that the two types of knowledge are independent. To compare with the previous study, ω1, ω2, β1 and β2 are set as ω1 = 0.5, ω2 = 0.5, β1 = β2 = 88%, which implies that Vi transfers two types of independent knowledge and the weight of each type of knowledge is 50%

Figure 1 show the experimental results of the DEP before knowledge transfer (DEPb), DEP after knowledge transfer (DEPa), transfer cost and the total DEP. Because experimental results in Fig. 1 are the same as described by Wu et al.27, the model is valid:

Let ω1 = 0.5, ω2 = 0.5, β1 = 88%, β2 = 84% and change the influence coefficient σ from σ = 0 to σ = 0.5, which indicates that the relationship between the two types of knowledge changes from independent to complementary. Figure 2 and 3 show the variation of the experimental results of the variables from 1-10. From the experimental results in Fig. 2 and 3, the DEP before knowledge transfer (DEPb) in Fig. 2 are the same as in Fig. 3; the DEP after knowledge transfer (DEPa), transfer cost and the total DEP in Fig. 3 are much greater than the values of the variables in Fig. 2. As the complementary types of knowledge are conducive to mutual efficiency, the profits increase proves the validity of the model

Fig. 1:Changes in DEP and transfer cost with σ = 0, β1 = β2 = 88%

Fig. 2:Changes in DEP and transfer cost with σ = 0, β2 = 84%

Simulation with influence coefficient as a variable: To determine the degree of the coefficient’s influence on the DEP and transfer cost, the weights of the two types of complementary knowledge ω1, ω2 are set as ω1 = 0.5, ω2 = 0.5, weighting private knowledge and big-data knowledge equally and each type of knowledge accounts for 50% of the total. All parameters except σ have the same values and the influence coefficient σ changes from σ = 0.1 to σ = 10.

Figure 4 and 5 show the total DEP and the transfer cost varying with σ from 0.1-10. The total DEP and the transfer cost will increase when the influence coefficient σ is enhanced. Thus, when the influence coefficient of dualistic complementary knowledge is enhanced, profits and transfer costs increase because the greater the mutual influence between the types of complementary knowledge is the more knowledge is transferred and transfer costs increase with profits.

Fig. 3:Changes in DEP and transfer cost with σ = 0.5, β2 = 84%

Fig. 4:Changes in total DEP with σ

Fig. 5:Changes in transfer cost with σ

Fig. 6:Changes in total DEP with ω1, ω2

The influence coefficient can be greater than 1. If the influence coefficient of the dualistic complementary knowledge is greater than 1, the degree of influence of the two types of knowledge is above the average influence level.

Simulation with the weights of two types of knowledge: To determine how much influence the weights of the two types of complementary knowledge have on the DEP and transfer cost, the influence coefficient is set as σ = 0.5. This value indicates that there is mutual influence between the two types of complementary knowledge. All parameters except ω1, ω2 are set with the same values. Figure 6 show that the total DEP varies with the weights of the two types of complementary knowledge. Figure 7 show that the transfer costs vary with the weights of the two types of complementary knowledge, ω2 = 0.1 is used to express ω1 = 0.9, ω2 = 0.1, etc. By enhancing the weight of big-data knowledge, the total DEP in Fig. 6 increases but the transfer costs in Fig. 7 decline. Big-data knowledge can help enterprises in decision-making, trimming costs and lifting sales21. The simulation’s experimental results are also in accordance with the actual economic situation.

Fig. 7:Changes in transfer cost with ω1, ω2

The models can provide decision-making support for solving dualistic complementary knowledge transfer problems in a big-data environment.

DISCUSSION

Currently, no study exists on complementary knowledge transfer in big-data environments. The literature on decision-making problems related to knowledge transfer in big-data environments focus on two types of independent knowledge27. Many results from qualitative research provide proof of the importance of knowledge complementarity for the formation of cooperation32-36. Scholars have analyzed the technology knowledge diffusion of related technologies by using the Bass model or Lotka-Volterra model37-40, which are primarily concerned with technical knowledge diffusion in the whole market and are rarely used to focus on changes to knowledge transfer efficiency for enterprises that have adopted new technical knowledge.

The experimental results of the simulation predicted the expected profits and transfer costs according to different influence coefficients and dualistic complementary knowledge weights. These predictions can be verified in actual economic situations.

CONCLUSION

In this study, the problem of complementary knowledge transfer in big-data environments is analyzed. Based on this analysis, models of dualistic complementary knowledge transfer are developed. Some parameters are given to verify the validity of the models. The calculation results are the same as those of previous studies, which do not consider the mutual influence of these two types of knowledge. Forecasts are developed for different influence coefficients and dualistic complementary knowledge weights. The experimental results of the simulation are consistent with an actual economic situation. The results of the present study can help enterprises understand the degree of mutual influence between the two types of complementary knowledge and determine the appropriate proportion of dualistic complementary knowledge when transferring knowledge in big-data environments.

Clearly, this study is focused on the linear relationship of the influence between the two types of dualistic complementary knowledge in a big-data environment. While, such a hypothesis could introduce calculative deviation, it is important to analyze the nonlinear relationship between private knowledge and big-data knowledge.

SIGNIFICANT STATEMENTS

The need to analyze the mutual influence of two types of complementary knowledge is considered
Models of dualistic complementary knowledge transfer are presented and the validity of the models is verified
Forecasts are developed for different influence coefficients and dualistic complementary knowledge weights
The results of this study can help enterprises understand the mutual influence of these two types of complementary knowledge and determine the proportion of dualistic complementary knowledge according to the degree of mutual influence and discounted profits when transferring knowledge in a big-data environment

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

This study is supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (Grant No. 71373032), the Natural Science Foundation of Hunan Province (Grant No. 12JJ4073), the Scientific Research Fund of Hunan Provincial Education Department (Grant No. 11C0029), the Educational Economy and Financial Research Base of Hunan Province (Grant No. 13JCJA2) and the Project of China Scholarship Council for Overseas Studies (201208430233 and 201508430121).

REFERENCES

  • Khamseh, H.M. and D. Jolly, 2014. Knowledge transfer in alliances: The moderating role of the alliance type. Knowledge Manage. Res. Pract., 12: 409-420.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Karlsen, J.T. and P. Gottschalk, 2004. Factors affecting knowledge transfer in IT projects. Eng. Manage. J., 16: 3-11.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Szulanski, G., 2000. The process of knowledge transfer: A diachronic analysis of stickiness. Organiz. Behav. Hum. Decis. Process., 82: 9-27.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Van Burg, E., H. Berends and E.M. van Raaij, 2014. Framing and interorganizational knowledge transfer: A process study of collaborative innovation in the aircraft industry. J. Manage. Stud., 51: 349-378.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Song, J., 2014. Subsidiary absorptive capacity and knowledge transfer within multinational corporations. J. Int. Bus. Stud., 45: 73-84.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Argote, L. and E. Fahrenkopf, 2016. Knowledge transfer in organizations: The roles of members, tasks, tools and networks. Organ. Behav. Hum. Decis. Proc., 136: 146-159.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Chen, C.J., 2008. The effects of knowledge attribute, alliance characteristics and absorptive capacity on knowledge transfer performance. R&D Manage., 34: 311-321.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Muthusamy, S.K. and M.A. White, 2005. Learning and knowledge transfer in strategic alliances: A social exchange view. Organiz. Stud., 26: 415-441.
    Direct Link    


  • Wu, W.L. and Y.C. Lee, 2015. Knowledge transfer and creation in international strategic alliances: A multi-level perspective. Int. J. Knowledge Manage. Stud., 6: 1-15.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Segers, J.P., 2015. The interplay between new technology based firms, strategic alliances and open innovation, within a regional systems of innovation context. The case of the biotechnology cluster in Belgium. J. Global Entrepreneurship Res., 5: 1-17.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • De Arteche, M., M. Santucci and S.V. Welsh, 2013. Clusters and networks for innovation and knowledge transfer. Impacton argentinean regional growth. Estud. Gerenc., 29: 127-138.
    Direct Link    


  • Ratten, V., 2015. International collaboration and knowledge transfer among universities and firms affecting regional competitiveness. Thunderbird Int. Bus. Rev., 1: 205-207.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Pirnau, C., M.A. Botezat and I.S. Grigorescu, 2016. Databases role correlated with knowledge transfer between entities of a cluster. Int. Reg. Sci. Rev., 19: 476-483.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Belso-Martinez, J.A., 2015. Resources, governance and knowledge transfer in Spanish footwear clusters can local firms be locked out by their crucial partner? Int. Reg. Sci. Rev., 38: 202-231.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Cowan, R. and N. Jonard, 2004. Network structure and the diffusion of knowledge. J. Econ. Dynam. Control, 28: 1557-1575.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Fritsch, M. and M. Kauffeld-Monz, 2010. The impact of network structure on knowledge transfer: An application of social network analysis in the context of regional innovation networks. Ann. Reg. Sci., 44: 21-38.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Tang, F., J. Mu and D.L. Maclachlan, 2010. Disseminative capacity, organizational structure and knowledge transfer. Expert Syst. Applic., 37: 1586-1593.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Wu, C.R. and Y.W. Chen, 2013. Time optimization of knowledge transfer in high-tech enterprises innovation networks. Syst. Eng. Theory Pract., 4: 955-962.
    Direct Link    


  • Bagheri, S., R.J. Kusters and J.J.M. Trienekens, 2016. An integrated framework of knowledge transfer and ICT issues in co-creation value networks. Procedia Comput. Sci., 100: 677-685.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • McGuire, T., J. Manyika and M. Chui, 2012. Why big data is the new competitive advantage. Ivey Bus. J., 76: 1-4.
    Direct Link    


  • Lohr, S., 2012. The age of big data. New York Times, February 2012. http://www.nytimes.com/2012/02/12/sunday-review/big-datas-impact-in-the-world.html.


  • Suchanek, F. and G. Weikum, 2013. Knowledge harvesting in the big-data era. Proceedings of the 2013 ACM SIGMOD International Conference on Management of Data, June 22-27, 2013, New York, USA., pp: 933-938.


  • Horst, P. and R. Duboff, 2015. Don't let big data bury your brand. Harv. Bus. Rev., 93: 78-86.


  • Jun, S., S. Park and D. Jang, 2015. A technology valuation model using quantitative patent analysis: A case study of technology transfer in big data marketing. Emerging Markets Finance Trade, 51: 963-974.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Manyika, J., M. Chui, B. Brown, J. Bughin, R. Dobbs, C. Roxburgh and A.H. Byers, 2011. Big data: The next frontier for innovation, competition and productivity. Report, McKinsey Global Institute (MGI), USA., May 2011.


  • Dutton, W., K. Pister, H. Varian, R. Bernard and R. Salkowitz et al., 2010. Clouds, big data and smart assets: Ten tech-enabled business trends to watch. McKinsey Quart., 4: 26-43.
    Direct Link    


  • Wu, C., Y. Chen and F. Li, 2016. Decision model of knowledge transfer in big data environment. China Commun., 13: 100-107.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Zuech, R., T.M. Khoshgoftaar and R. Wald, 2015. Intrusion detection and big heterogeneous data: A survey. J. Big Data, Vol. 2.
    CrossRef    


  • Wu, X., X. Zhu, G.Q. Wu and W. Ding, 2014. Data mining with big data. IEEE Trans. Knowledge Data Eng., 26: 97-107.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Wu, C. and D. Zeng, 2009. Knowledge transfer optimization simulation for innovation networks Inform. Technol. J., 8: 589-594.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Hai, Z., W. Guo and X. Li, 2007. The potential energy of knowledge flow. Concurrency Computat. Pract. Exp., 19: 2067-2090.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Kim, K.K., H.K. Shin and M.H. Lee, 2010. The influence of partner knowledge complementarities on the effectiveness of IT outsourcing. J. Organ. Comput. Electron. Commerce, 20: 213-233.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Tu, K.J., 2014. Synergy optimization and operation management on syndicate complementary knowledge cooperation. AIP Conf. Proc., 1618: 433-435.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Cassiman, B. and G. Valentini, 2015. Open innovation: Are inbound and outbound knowledge flows really complementary? Strat. Manage. J., 37: 1034-1046.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Kavusan, K., N.G. Noorderhaven and G.M. Duysters, 2016. Knowledge acquisition and complementary specialization in alliances: The impact of technological overlap and alliance experience. Res. Policy, 45: 2153-2165.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Caminati, M., 2016. Knowledge specialization and R&D collaboration. J. Evol. Econ., 26: 247-270.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Kim, D.H., Y.G. Shin, S.S. Park and D.S. Jang, 2009. Forecasting diffusion of technology by using bass model. AIP Conf. Proc., 1148: 149-152.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Barkoczi, N., M. Lobontiu and L. Bacali, 2015. Predicting the adoption by the young consumers of a new technology on the mobile phone market using the bass diffusion model. Rev. Manage. Econ. Eng., 14: 297-306.
    Direct Link    


  • Geroski, P.A., 2000. Models of technology diffusion. Res. Policy, 29: 603-625.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Ganguly, S., 2015. Inter-temporal correlation structure of cross-country technology diffusion: An application of the generalized lotka-volterra model. Working Paper, Social Science Electronic Publishing, December, 2015.

  • © Science Alert. All Rights Reserved