HOME JOURNALS CONTACT

The International Journal of Applied Economics and Finance

Year: 2016 | Volume: 10 | Issue: 1-3 | Page No.: 14-20
DOI: 10.3923/ijaef.2016.14.20
Leasing in the Automobile Industry: Who Lease Cars
Arif Sultan

Abstract: This study extends Kim model in a previous study of the used car market with asymmetric information to examine the possible impacts of leasing and warranty on adverse selection which affects the functioning of the car market by influencing the average quality of traded cars sold in the market. Kim model assumed that the quality of cars depends on the maintenance level. Like model by Kim and other previous studies assumed that the quality of cars depends on the maintenance level but the maintenance level is chosen when cars are still "new" cars i.e., after the warranty ends. This study assumes that consumers can buy or lease new cars, or they can buy used or Certified Pre-Owned (CPO) cars and the maintenance level for leased cars is specified in the leasing contract, while that of purchased cars is chosen by consumers after the warranty expires. The model implied that the average quality of traded cars can be either higher or lower than the average quality of non-traded cars which is partly because of leasing, warranty and CPO besides other factors, indicating that these institutions have improved the information mechanism between buyers and sellers of used cars which, in turn, has helped in reducing adverse selection and improving the average quality of traded cars in the market. The study also uses a modified version of a previous study in which lemon model used to test the quality of traded and non-traded cars in the market. To deal with the censoring problem in the data, a tobit model is used and sensitivity analysis is applied to check the robustness of the coefficients. The data is collected from "The Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID)" from the University of Michigan for this study. The results show that the average quality of traded cars is not significantly different than that of non-traded cars, all else equal, indicating that traded cars required same maintenance expenditures as non-traded cars of a similar age.

Fulltext PDF Fulltext HTML

How to cite this article
Arif Sultan , 2016. Leasing in the Automobile Industry: Who Lease Cars. The International Journal of Applied Economics and Finance, 10: 14-20.

Keywords: product quality, lemon model, institutions, inter-temporal consumer choice and Asymmetric information

INTRODUCTION

Adverse selection can cause inefficiency in the functioning of a market as suggested by Akerlof (1970) in his seminal study on the lemons market. Inefficiency in a market can arise when price varies with quality of a car and there is no single equilibrium price prevailing in the market. So, the average quality of a car depends on the price and this may lead to adverse selection which happens when trade takes place between an informed (seller of a car) and uninformed (buyer of a car) agent in a manner that adversely affects the uninformed agent in the market because of unobservable characteristics of a car.

Because of asymmetric information between buyers and sellers of cars, sellers of good cars are willing to sell their cars at a certain price, not below that price. But buyers are not willing to buy cars of average quality at that price, because they are unable to discern lemons from good cars. The presence of sufficient amount of bad cars in the market pushes the price down below that certain price which in turn drives the good cars out of the market. When the good cars are driven out of the market, the average quality of the remaining cars in the market fall and this further lowers the price that buyers are willing to pay. This process of driving out the good cars may lead to a point where there is no trade in the market: "The bad cars tend to drive out the good" as suggested by Akerlof (1970). By assuming a positive volume of trade, Wilson (1980) showed a nontrivial equilibrium in the used car market. Thus, the lemons hypothesis can be reinterpreted as saying that the average quality of non-traded cars is higher than that of traded cars. In the used car market context, Akerlof (1970) suggested that in this situation private institutions can emerge in order to provide information to buyers about the quality of cars and these institutions can improve the functioning of a market but they may not be able to eliminate market failure completely caused by asymmetric information.

Leasing in the automobile industry has been growing rapidly in the last 20 years. For example, consumer leasing as a percentage of the number of cars acquired was 9.3% in 1992 which increased to 20% in 2002 and it further went up to 22% in 20101. Many leasing contracts have two prices: A rental price and an option price and they also provide two options to a lessee at termination of the lease: Return the cars at no cost or keep them by paying the option price. Most car leases are two to three years long and studies show that only 25% of lessees keep their cars at maturity (Hendel and Lizzeri, 2002), implying that lessees hold onto their cars for shorter periods than car buyers. In fact, many off-leased cars are still under a manufacturer’s warranty at the time they are returned.

Certified Pre-Owned (CPO) programs2 aim to refurbish the off-leased vehicles after a multi-step inspection and provide an extended warranty. Most off-leased cars are inspected, refurbished and resold as CPO cars. In recent years, the industry witnessed about a 20% increase in sales of CPO vehicle

With these changes, the automobile industry is a different market segment now as compared to many years ago. So, the motivation of doing this study is the fact that there might be a different answer to the lemons hypothesis. Thus, the first question to consider is this: Is the average quality of non-traded cars still higher than that of traded cars? The second question is as follows: What impact do leasing, warranty and CPO have on the adverse selection phenomenon prevailing in the used car market? To examine these questions, this study extends Kim (1985) and Sultan (2010) models of the used car market with asymmetric information.

The role of leasing was examined by Gilligan (2004) and he found evidence that leasing mitigates the consequences of asymmetric information about the quality uncertainty of used durable goods. Hendel and Lizzeri (2002) showed that the turnover of off-leased cars is higher than that of other used cars, implying leasing contracts can improve inefficiency caused by asymmetric information. Johnson and Waldman (2003) showed that leasing reduces the adverse selection problem. Further evidence was provided by Alzcorbe and Starr-McCluer (1997) and Starkey (1997); they found that the higher income consumers prefer leasing to buying. Desai and Purohit (1998) also found that off-leased cars are of higher average quality than other used cars. This study provides a theoretical support to these findings by showing that the average quality of traded cars can be either higher or lower than the average quality of non-traded cars and that the institutions of leasing, warranty and CPO have helped in improving the information mechanism between buyers and sellers of used cars which have resulted in reducing adverse selection in the market (Fig. 1).

Fig. 1: Model of vehicle acquisition

EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS

Bond (1982) tested the lemons hypothesis (whether the average quality of traded and non-traded cars is the same) by using data from the Truck Inventory and Use Survey of the Census of Transportation with frequency of maintenance as dependent variable while mileage, age of car and "traded" as independent variables and he finds no support for the lemons hypothesis. Lacko (1986) finds some evidence of adverse selection by comparing the quality of cars purchased from friends and those that were purchased through newspaper ads. He finds that cars purchased from friends and relatives require less maintenance expenditures than cars purchased through newspaper ads. Comparing prices of cars that are sold by New Car Dealers (NCDs) and Used Car Dealers (UCDs) at the wholesale auctions, Genesove (1993) finds that NCDs receive premium over UCDs for the cars of same model and quality, implying weak evidence of adverse selection. Pratt and Hoffer (1986) investigated whether the quality certification and the used vehicle disclosure laws required by certain states are effective or not? They find that there is no evidence that the mandated disclosure requirements in certain states are effective in increasing the number of good quality trucks traded in the market.

METHODOLOGY

This study uses the following model which is an extended version of Bond (1982):

(1)

where, M = Maintenance expenditure incurred on a car and is computed by dividing maintenance expenditures with number of cars in a household (Sultan, 2008) which is a proxy for the quality of a car; TRADED is a dummy variable equaling 1 if the car acquired was used and 0 otherwise; AGEC represents age of a car; SEX OF HEAD is a dummy variable equaling 1 if the head was male and 0 otherwise; AGE OF HOUSE HOLD represents age of head of the household; Marital STATUS OF HEAD is a dummy variable equaling 1 if the head was married and 0 otherwise; VEHICLE TYPE is a dummy variable equaling 1 if the vehicle acquired was car and 0 otherwise; RACE OF HEAD is a dummy variable equaling 1 if the head was white and 0 otherwise; HIGH SCHOOL GRADUATE is a dummy variable equaling 1 if the head was high school graduate and 0 otherwise; similarly, COLLEGE GRADUATE is a dummy variable equaling 1 if the head was college graduate and 0 otherwise; INCOME is income of the household and SYEAR is a dummy variable for survey year. Unlike Sultan (2008), this model has more socio-economic variables reflecting on a consumer’s choice of vehicle type.

A car requiring more than average maintenance expenditure is considered a lemon, whereas a car requiring less than average expenditure is a good car. The presence of a positive and significant value of the coefficient of TRADED β1 indicates that a traded car is likely to have more maintenance expenditure than a non-traded car, all else being equal. Alternatively, the presence of a negative and significant value of β1 indicates that a traded car is likely to have less maintenance expenditure than a non-traded car. If β1 is insignificant, then there is no significant difference in the maintenance expenditures between a traded and a non-traded car. β1 is expected to be not significantly different from zero.

This study tests the hypothesis of no difference in the average maintenance expenditures required for traded and non-traded cars. The alternative hypothesis is that the average maintenance expenditures required for traded cars is lower than that of non-traded cars. If the null hypothesis is rejected, that implies that the quality of traded cars is better than non-traded cars. The above model is estimated using the Tobit method instead of the OLS method because there are almost half of cars in the sample having zero maintenance expenditure. If the model is estimated using OLS, because of the large number (proportion) of zero maintenance, the estimates will be biased and inconsistent, since there is no guarantee that E(ε) will be necessarily zero. As shown in Table 1, approximately half of the cars in the sample do not require any maintenance expenditure.

To deal with this censoring, a Tobit model is estimated because the Tobit model assumes that the structure of the error term as ε~N (0, σ2), where σ2 is the variance of the error term.

There is a common notion that as a car gets older, more maintenance expenditure it would require. Akerlof (1970) lemons model gives no specific guidance about how long would it take a car owner to become aware that his car is a lemon. Among the older cars, many of lemons may already have been scrapped. Many newer cars may still have warranty so age of a car must be controlled for. So, age of the cars is an explanatory variable to take care of the issue.

INCOME, EDUCATION, ETHNICITY, MARITAL STATUS, VEHICLE TYPE AND AGE OF HOUSEHOLD variables are also added to the list of explanatory variables as they are also expected to affect the maintenance expenditure incurred on a car which is a dependant variable.

Four versions of the model are estimated. First, I estimate the model separately for traded and non-traded cars to compare their intercepts and slopes, second, I estimate the model with INCOME and AGE OF HOUSEHOLD variables and some other socio-economic variables, third, I add both INCOME and AGE OF HOUSEHOLD and squared of these two variables in the model. The variables INCOME SQUARED and AGE SQUARED are added to see the non-linearity effects between these variables and the dependent variable. This procedure allows us to better understand the effect of these variables on the estimate of car maintenance expenditure. Fourth, I estimate the model for traded cars of age 10 years and above.

RESULTS

Data description: This empirical analysis draws bi-annual survey data for years 1999 and 2001 from sections V and X and for years 2003-2009 from section F of "The Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID)" from the University of Michigan. The data about vehicles are taken from sections V and F, while data on maintenance expenditures are taken from sections X and F. These sections have been a part of the survey since 1999. The sample covers total of 40,565 cars for years 1999-2009. The households who do not own a car are not included.

Table 1 contains the summary statistics. It shows that the proportion of used cars that required maintenance expenditures is 27.5%, while only 17.5% new cars required maintenance expenditures. Fifty eight percent of cars in the sample were acquired used, whereas 42% of them were purchased new. Forty five percent of cars in the sample required any maintenance expenditures.

Descriptive statistics for the data is presented in Table 2. It shows that the average monthly maintenance expenditure for the used car in the household is about 284 d$, while it is about 270 $ per month for the new car. The average price of the car acquired new is 18,112 $, whereas the average price of used car is 7,149 $. Average Age of the households who bought new cars is 47.92, 47% of them are college graduates, 73% of them are white and their average annual income is 90,202 $; while average age of those household who bought used cars is 42.43 and their average annual income is 51,567 $.

Table 1: Summary statistics

Table 2: Descriptive statistics

Table 3: Tobit estimates (Combined data) (Eq. 1)
Z-statistics are in parentheses, ***Denotes significance at 1% level, **Denotes significance at 5% level and *Denotes significance at 10% level, Column 1 reports tobit estimates, columns 2 reports tobit estimates with additional explanatory variables and column 3 reports tobit estimates for traded cars of age 10 years and above

DISCUSSION

The results are presented in Table 3. As shown in the table, both traded and non-traded have negative and significant constant terms but slope of traded is positive, while that of non-traded is negative, implying that non-traded require less maintenance expenditures as compared to traded cars. Column 1 of Table 3 shows that the estimated coefficient of β1 = 0.001 (z = 0.41) is negative and insignificant as expected implying that there is no difference in the maintenance expenditures between traded and non-traded car of a similar age. In the second column we show the result by adding squared of both AGE OF HOUSEHOLD and INCOME variables to the basic model. As displayed in column 2 of Table 3, the estimated coefficient of TRADED is β1 = 0.001 (z = 0.44). The estimated coefficient of TRADED is positive and insignificant. This indicates that the average quality of a traded car is same as that of non-traded car.

Next, I estimate the model by taking traded cars of age 10 years and above and find that the estimated coefficient of TRADED 0.004 (z = 1.45) is positive and significant at the 10% level of significance, indicating that the average maintenance expenditures incurred on traded and non-traded car is not the same. This indicates that maintenance expenditure is significantly different for both types of cars-traded and non-traded.

Table 3 also shows that the variables male, white and high school graduate are positively associated with maintenance expenditures, while the variables age of household, income, marital status and college graduate are negatively associated with maintenance expenditures, indicating that they prefer new cars.

To test the hypothesis of the stability of parameters, we find the F-Statistic to be 0.931. Thus, the stability hypothesis cannot be rejected at the 10% level of significance, implying strong possibility of pooling. Therefore, the results from the combined data are presented only.

Sensitivity analysis: Sensitivity analysis is carried out to examine whether the estimates are robust to alternative model specifications. In general, the parameter estimates are robust. In particular, the estimated coefficient for the variable, TRADED remains positive and insignificant.

First, I estimate the model using OLS4 with different specification choices and find that the results are very similar to the baseline results from Tobit, where the baseline results are displayed in column 1 of Table 3.

Second, I estimate the Tobit and OLS5 models by adding more explanatory variables and find that the results are still very similar to the baseline results as shown in Table 3. The result shows that the coefficient estimate of TRADED is positive and statistically insignificant. With INCOME and INCOME SQUARED as new explanatory variables, the estimated coefficient of TRADED remains the same.

CONCLUSION

In this study, a simple theory of a used car market with leasing, warranty and adverse selection is developed. The analysis implies that the average quality of traded cars can be either higher or lower than the average quality of non-traded used. This means that the Lemons Principle may or may not hold. These results are sensitive to the nature of g (m) and h (m) functions and the valuations attached by the consumers to the quality of a car and the maintenance level chosen for it.

This finding is not consistent with the common perception that the cars are sold when they become expensive to maintain. One possible explanation is the institutions (such as leasing, warranty and CPO) to counteract quality uncertainty as suggested by Akerlof. Higher income consumers prefer leasing their cars and they off-lease their cars at the expiry of the leasing contract and these cars are refurbished before selling as CPO cars. Hence, used car market is not overabundanced with lemons as envisaged by Akerlof (1970). However, this is not entirely because of the institutions of leasing, warranty and CPO. There are also some other contributing factors such as maintenance level and valuations of consumers for car service. In addition, there are some higher valuation consumers who buy new cars in every period and choose high levels of maintenance in order to get good service from their cars and they sell them after one period and buy new cars again to continue having good service from their cars. Thus, they supply good quality used cars in the market.

This study also examines the difference in the quality between traded and non-traded cars. The quality of a car is determined by measuring maintenance expenditure incurred on a car. The study finds that traded cars require same maintenance expenditure as non-traded cars, all else equal. This result is consistent with earlier empirical testing by Bond (1982), Lacko (1986) and Genesove (1993).

ACKNOWLEDGMENTS

I thank Profs. Li Way Lee, Ralph Braid, Tomomi Kumagai and Sheng-Kai Chang for helpful comments on an earlier version of this study. Also, I thank to the participants of a seminar at the Wayne State University for helpful comments.

1For details, see Automotive News, CNW Marketing/Research and The Used Car Market Reports by Manheim Auctions
2For details, see the following websites: http://www.kbb.com; http://www.endmunds.com; http://www.jdpower.com; http://www.polk.com; and http://www.nvo.com/cnwmr/
3For details, see Automotive News, Industry Trade Reports and The Used Car Market Reports by Manheim Auctions
4These results are not reported to save the space but available upon request for the authors
5Again I did not report these results here to save space

REFERENCES

  • Alzcorbe, A. and M. Starr-McCluer, 1997. Vehicle ownership, purchases and leasing: Consumer survey data. Monthly Lab. Rev., 120: 34-40.
    Direct Link    


  • Akerlof, G.A., 1970. The market for Lemons: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism. Q. J. Econ., 84: 488-500.
    Direct Link    


  • Bond, E.W., 1982. A direct test of the Lemons model: The market for used pickup trucks. Am. Econ. Rev., 72: 836-840.
    Direct Link    


  • Desai, P. and D. Purohit, 1998. Leasing and selling: Optimal marketing strategies for a durable goods firm. Manage. Sci., 44: S19-S34.
    Direct Link    


  • Genesove, D., 1993. Adverse selection in the wholesale used car market. J. Political Econ., 101: 644-665.
    Direct Link    


  • Gilligan, T.W., 2004. Lemons and leases in the used business aircraft market. J. Political Econ., 112: 1157-1180.
    Direct Link    


  • Hendel, I. and A. Lizzeri, 2002. The role of leasing under adverse selection. Nat. Bureau Econ. Res., 110: 113-143.
    Direct Link    


  • Johnson, J.P. and M. Waldman, 2003. Leasing, lemons and buybacks. RAND J. Econ., 34: 247-265.
    Direct Link    


  • Kim, J.C., 1985. The market for Lemons reconsidered: A model of the used car market with asymmetric information. Am. Econ. Rev., 75: 836-843.
    Direct Link    


  • Lacko, J.M., 1986. Product quality and information in the used car market. Bureau of Economics Staff Report to the Federal Trade Commission, April 1986.


  • Pratt, M.D. and G.E. Hoffer, 1986. The efficacy of state mandated minimum quality certification: The case of used vehicles. Econ. Inquiry, 24: 313-318.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Starkey, W.S., 1997. Automobile leasing in the United States: Why do consumers lease cars? Ph.D. Thesis, University of Washington, Washington, DC.


  • Sultan, A., 2008. Lemons hypothesis reconsidered: An empirical analysis. Econ. Lett., 99: 541-544.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Sultan, A., 2010. A model of the used car market with lemons and leasing. Applied Econ., 42: 3619-3627.
    CrossRef    Direct Link    


  • Wilson, C., 1980. The nature of equilibrium in markets with adverse selection. Bell J. Econ., 11: 108-130.
    Direct Link    

  • © Science Alert. All Rights Reserved