INTRODUCTION
The financial literature on mutual fund performance has developed significantly
alongside the growth of the funds industry. One stream of research in this literature
concerns the market timing ability of mutual funds. Correct (perverse) timing
implies that managers increase (decrease) fund risk to anticipate an upward
(downward) stock market. When evaluation of market timing is based on returns
data, a model is generally introduced that explains how the fund returns are
generated and how the timing decisions are incorporated. The most widely used
models in the literature involve a linear relation between the fund returns
and the market. Taking the linear model as a base, the most common procedure
in the literature is to introduce a quadratic term to measure market timing
(Holmes and Faff, 2004). Thus, the beta of the fund is
equal to a constant and a slope with respect to market return. Correct (perverse)
timing implies an increase (decrease) in the beta in an upward (downward) market.
On the other hand, Henriksson and Merton (1981) propose
a model with two levels of beta, for up and down markets, respectively. A large
number of empirical studies have applied these models and others derived from
them, to measure market timing. These studies, from Henriksson
and Merton (1981) to Holmes and Faff (2004), do not find evidence of timing
in general, but in some cases find perverse timing. Ferson
and Schadt (1996) also used returns although with a different methodology;
in general they find no evidence of timing, but in some cases positive timing
was found. These researchers propose a conditional approach that allows a variable
beta over time according to managers response to public market information.
Matallín (2008) also proposes a time varying beta to evaluate portfolio
timing. These studies show how a beta that is not constant over time can provoke
artificial timing. To avoid this, market timing should be evaluated over short
periods. Benos and Jochec (2008) use daily return data
to look for persistence in the ability of mutual funds to time the market, finding
persistence only among well performing funds.
In general, earlier evaluations of market timing ability have proposed models,
with either a constant or time-varying beta, that consider simultaneous timing.
That is, these models compare the beta in a period with the market return in
the same period. However, the portfolio management in a period could be a forecast
of market movements in upcoming periods. For example, consider a manager that
times an upward market in the next period and increases the beta of the portfolio
at the beginning of the t day. The situation may occur in which the market does
not rise on this day, but it rises sharply on following days. If simultaneous
days are compared, the evidence will be of no timing, although timing has taken
place. This problem could be solved by measuring timing over wide periods. However,
Goetzmann et al. (2000) and Bollen
and Busse (2001) showed how the evaluation of short term timing could be
biased when it is measured over wide periods. The present study aims to solve
non-simultaneous timing by measuring it over windows of varying length ranges.
DATA AND MUTUAL FUND SAMPLE
In the empirical section of the study, a sample of Spanish mutual funds
(FIM, Fondos de Inversión Mobiliaria) is analysed. Mutual fund
daily net share values, from July 1998 to September 2004, were provided
by the Spanish Stock Market National Commission (CNMV). The sample was
made up of all the risky mutual funds in the period sample, specifically
79 mutual funds that mainly invest in equities in the domestic stock market.
The IGBM, the Madrid Stock Exchange Index, was used as a proxy for the
Spanish stock market. This value-weighted index was chosen because it
holds a large number of equities and may better represent the diversified
portfolios of the sample mutual funds. The return implicit in T-bills
repos is used as risk-free return. The data sources used were Internet
information providers from the Madrid Stock Exchange and the Analistas
Financieros Internacionales (AFI).
In addition, the effect of omitted benchmarks when evaluating market timing
is also considered. To do this, an additional, equally-weighted benchmark is
constructed with medium and small cap stocks, (EMS benchmark). Harvey
and Siddique (2000) and Barone-Adesi et al. (2004)
have shown how small stocks present negative coskewness with respect to the
market. If this is not controlled for, even in a passive portfolio without timing
management, artificial evidence of negative timing may be found because the
assets held by the fund show this behaviour. Daily returns from stock prices
data, provided by Intertell, are used to construct the EMS benchmark.
This study presents the results for both the individual mutual funds
and the two aggregated portfolios constructed with all the mutual funds
in the sample. The first aggregate portfolio is an equally-weighted fund
(EF) and the second, a size-weighted fund (SF), where the size is measured
as the funds asset value.
The literature on Spanish mutual funds focuses on performance. Marin
and Rubio (2001) utilised both unconditional and conditional models; Martinez
(2003) studied the effect of portfolio restrictions in mutual funds;
Ferruz and Sarto (2004) assessed the inconsistence of Sharpes ratio
in some cases; Ferruz et al. (2005) analysed the
positive effect that international diversification has on performance and Ciriaco
and Santamaría (2005) analysed persistence in performance.
MATERIALS AND METHODS
To measure market timing, we follow the approach of Mataliín
(2005, 2008). As in many other studies, this study
evaluates market timing from mutual funds excess return data (rpt)
and market excess return data (rmt) and in Eq. 1,
assumes a linear relation between the two. As this relation could be time-varying,
we consider the possibility of endogenous changes in the beta of the mutual
fund portfolio (βpt). Given that the beta is not observable
and must therefore be estimated, the Kalman filter provides an appropriate methodology.
In this context, Eq. 1 represents the measurement equation
and Eq. 2 is the transition equation of the state variable
βpt over time. As in other studies, such as Wells
(1996), Brooks et al. (1998) and McKenzie
et al. (2000), that apply the Kalman filter to estimate betas, in
Eq. 3 we assume that the portfolio beta follows a random walk
in expected terms. So, βpt+1/t is the prediction of beta at
moment t+1 given the existing information up to t and βpt/t
the beta at t from the information available up to moment t. The parameters
of the system Eq. 1-3 and others of the Kalman
filter methodology are estimated for each mutual fund by maximum likelihood,
following Koopman et al. (1999) and using the
BHHH (Berndt, Hall, Hall and Hausman) optimisation algorithm:
From the dynamic beta series estimated by Kalman filtering, the changes
in beta (Δβpt = βpt/t-βpt-1/t-1)
are calculated and then linked to market excess return in Eq.
4. If γp is significantly positive (negative), it
could be inferred as evidence of correct (perverse) market timing. To
control for the benchmark omission problem, model Eq. 5
is also considered, which introduces the changes in beta from the EMS
benchmark with respect to the market:
The above approach measures simultaneous timing, i.e., it compares the
change in beta and the market return on the same day. To evaluate non-simultaneous
timing, five additional accumulative windows are considered: 1 week, 2
weeks, 1 month, 3 months and 6 months. In this way, the simultaneous and
non-simultaneous timing for longer periods are analysed. These estimation
windows could be labelled from short-term timing to long-term timing.
Specifically, Eq. 6 shows the estimation of the variation
in the beta over a wide period from the changes in beta during the T days
within this wide period. The accumulative return on T days is calculated
through Eq. 7. The expressions Eq. 4
and 5 can then be transformed using ΔβptT,
rmtT and ΔβEMStT instead of Δβpt,
rmt and ΔβEMSt:
RESULTS AND DISCUSSION
Panel A of Table 1 shows the estimates of Eq.
4 for the aggregated portfolios. The first row, corresponding to the
1 day window, shows the results of the estimate of Eq. 4
for the simultaneous timing case. It can be observed that for both portfolios,
SF and EF, there is no significant evidence of market timing. For wider
length periods, the evidence of timing is greater. In general, the longer
the term analysed, the more significant the negative timing will be, especially
for the SF portfolio. This result implies that larger-sized funds show
greater evidence of negative timing.
Panel B of Table 1 presents the individual results, showing
the number of funds with positive or negative timing. These results confirm
the aggregated results. Thus, for the simultaneous timing, only 10 funds present
negative timing and no cases are positive. Moreover, when the length of the
window is increased, the number of funds with significant timing is greater,
especially negative cases.
Table 2 shows the results when the EMS benchmark, i.e.,
an equally-weighted portfolio with medium and small cap stocks, is considered
in Eq. 5. Panel A shows the aggregated results and the
dramatic drop in significance is noteworthy. For the SF portfolio timing
is only significant for the 6 month window. Timing is not significant
in any case for the EF portfolio. These results show how part of the previous
evidence of negative timing is driven passively by the assets that the
fund holds and not by fund management. The individual results are consistent
with the aggregates and the number of funds in which the timing is significant
diminishes severely. Thus, in general no evidence of timing is found for
the simultaneous case (1 day) and for the 1 week window. For the 2 week,
1 month and 3 month windows, there is slight evidence of significant timing,
both positive and negative. Only in the 6 month window does the previous
evidence in Table 1 without the EMS benchmark appear
to remain.
Table 1: |
Mutual fund market timing |
|
Analysis with Eq. 4 of market timing ability in Spanish equity
mutual funds from July 1998 to September 2004. The difference Δβpt is the variation in the daily beta estimated by the Kalman filter. Market timing
is evaluated by γp. Panel A shows the results for aggregate
funds. SF (EF) is a size (equally) weighted portfolio made up of mutual funds
in the sample. Panel B shows individual results. The p-value of each parameter
is given in parentheses. The heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent
covariance estimator by Newey and West (1987) |
In brief, these results would indicate that in general, mutual funds do not
time the market in the short term. Only for a longer, 6 month period do 33 (14)
funds out of 79% negative (positive) market timing. However, since managers
timing decisions are not observable, caution should be exercised. The only firm
conclusion is that for the 6 month window, the beta in 33 funds increased (decreased)
when the market was down (up) while for 14, the opposite occurred. These changes
in beta could be explained by factors other than market timing. Specifically,
it is important to consider the effect of passive portfolio management in longer
periods. Matallín and Fernández (2003)
demonstrate how passive portfolios can show evidence of market timing in a simultaneous
window when it is measured by the quadratic model. In the present case, if non-simultaneous
timing is measured, the effect of passive management becomes greater as the
window length increases. For example, suppose that a passive portfolio invests
50% in the stock index and 50% in T-Bills at the year beginning; thus the beta
is 0.5. If the stock index achieves good (bad) results during the semester,
the weight of the part invested in equities goes up (down) and the aggregate
beta of the portfolio will be higher (lower) than 0.5.
Table 2: |
Mutual fund market timing with previously omitted benchmark |
 |
Analysis with Eq. 5 of market timing ability
in equity Spanish mutual funds from July 1998 to September 2004. The difference
Δβpt is the variation in the daily beta estimated by
the Kalman filter. Market timing is evaluated by γp. The
EMS is an equally-weighted benchmark which represents medium and small cap
stocks. Panel A shows the results for aggregate funds. SF (EF) is a size
(equally) weighted portfolio made up of mutual funds in the sample. Panel
B shows individual results. The p-value of each parameter is given in parentheses.
The heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance estimator
is by Newey and West (1987) |
Then this portfolio will
evidence positive timing, because the beta has increased (decreased) when the
market has been up (down). To shows this, we simulate passive portfolios that
invest different weights in the IGBM stock index, the EMS benchmark and the
risk free asset. Once 81 simulated buy-and-hold portfolios have been formed,
returns are calculated and Eq. 5 is estimated for different
windows. Table 3 shows the results and it is clear that for
non-simultaneous windows, a buy-and-hold strategy generates evidence of positive
market timing. Implicit increases (decreases) in the daily beta of the portfolio,
resulting from the bull (bear) stock market in a wide window, imply a positive
relation between market return and beta variation in this window.
A comparison of the results of Table 2 and 3
suggests that in general the mutual funds do not follow a buy-and-hold
strategy and they rebalance their holdings to maintain a constant level
of systematic risk. This is logical behaviour if the mutual fund wants
to maintain a certain investment target. Consequently, mutual funds may
show evidence of positive market timing in the long term if they follow
a buy-and-hold strategy.
Table 3: |
Implicit timing in simulated passive portfolios |
 |
Analysis with (5) of market timing ability in simulated passive
(buy-and-hold strategy) portfolios that invest, with different weights,
in the IGBM stock index, the EMS benchmark and the risk free asset. Δβpt
is the variation in the daily beta estimated by means of the Kalman filter.
Market timing is evaluated by γp. The EMS is an equally-weighted
benchmark which represents medium and small cap stocks. The p-value of each
parameter is given in parentheses. The heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation
consistent covariance estimator is by Newey and West
(1987) |
If mutual funds readjust beta, compensating implicit
changes from a buy-and-hold strategy, the evidence will be of no market
timing. However, if in this latter case managers decisions could
be observed and only this information were considered, without taking
into account implicit changes, the beta readjustment will lead to evidence
of negative market timing. If mutual funds readjust beta in excess of
the compensation for the implicit changes from the buy-and-hold strategy,
negative market timing will be evidenced.
CONCLUSIONS
Mutual fund market timing is generally measured in a simultaneous window
in the short term; in other words, the changes in beta over a brief period
are compared with the market return at that moment. However, decisions
on beta could affect subsequent periods; this is termed non-simultaneous
timing. In the empirical study of a sample of Spanish mutual funds, the
dynamic beta is estimated with the Kalman filter. Market timing is analysed
by comparing changes in beta and market return. In the widest model, including
a small and medium stocks benchmark, no evidence of timing is found in
the simultaneous case. With larger windows, in the non-simultaneous case,
the number of funds with positive and negative timing increases. However,
in aggregate terms, no evidence of market timing is found for 1 week to
3 month windows. Only for the 6 month window is the evidence of negative
timing greater. When this result is compared with that achieved by passive
buy-and-hold portfolios, it seems that many mutual funds do not follow
this strategy and that they time the market negatively in the long term.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The author acknowledges the financial support provided by the Generalitat
Valenciana grant GV/2007/097 and the financial support provided by Ministerio
de Ciencia y Tecnología grant SEJ2007-67204/ECON.